When a sailor hits a dead spot where the wind refuses to
blow he cays he is “in irons.” Japan’s economy sailed into the irons this past
quarter when its GDP declined for the second quarter in a row and officially
signaled a recession. GDP fell 0.8% in the third quarter after shrinking 0.7%
in the second on an annualized basis. This marks the fourth recession Japan has
endured since the global crisis hit in 2008.
Following so soon on the heels of massive stimulus, the
recession should strike a death blow to mainstream monetary theory. Abenomics,
the economic recovery plan that Prime Minister Shinzo Abe launched in 2012, was
the poster child for mainstream monetary theory. Japan would wash away deflation
and decline with a torrent of new money.
Europe isn’t technically in a recession, but inflation has
fallen and growth is so low that the difference between growth and recession
may be difficult for the average European to grasp. The inflation rate in the
Big EZ is currently 0.1%. Frightened by deflation, the European Central Bank’s
head Mario Draghi promised to open the monetary spigot even further.
The top mainstream economists, all Nobel-Prize winners,
declared the end of the business cycle in the late 1990s after nearly a decade
of the “Great Moderation.” They announced that the US would never face major
downturns in the economy again because they had figured out how to use monetary
policy effectively. They took credit for creating the “Great Moderation” and
announced that monetary policy would quickly smother the fires of any minor
downturns in the economy.
The mild recession of 2001 did little to dent the confidence
of mainstream economists, but the Great Recession should have. Now Japan has
suffered another recession after the most complete implementation of their
policies outside of the US and Europe.
Of course, they have argued that the sales tax increases in
Japan derailed the monetary policy. But a reasonable person can be forgiven for
thinking that monetary policy must be awfully timid if a small sales tax
increase can frighten it away.
The real problem with modern monetary theory is that its
inventors have defined it in such a way that it’s impossible to test it. They
use Milton Friedman’s analogy of a car. Friedman said that monetary policy is
like a driver using the gas pedal to cause the car to speed up. On a flat road
in the desert, pushing on the gas pedal will cause the car (the economy) to
accelerate and releasing it will cause the car to slow down.
But in the mountains, pushing on the gas pedal may not cause
the car to speed up if it’s driving up a steep grade. The car may continue to
slow down as the driver pushes harder on the gas pedal but he isn’t pushing
hard enough to provide enough gas to the engine to make the car go faster. The
lesson is that the only way to tell if the Fed is providing enough gas to the
economy in the form of new money is if the nominal GDP is speeding up. No
matter what the Fed has done in the past, if nominal GDP is not accelerating
then the Fed has a tight monetary policy.
The analogy is great if one assumes that monetary policy is
omnipotent. But what if it’s not? What if monetary policy doesn’t work the way
mainstream economists claim? What if it causes more harm than good as Austrian
economists assert? How can we who have not drunk the Kool-Aid of mainstream
monetary theory test it?
Clearly, we can’t if we accept their analogy. It assumes its
conclusion, which is called circular reasoning in logic. It also assumes that
all economic growth comes exclusively from creating new money.
Another way to look at the economy is to compare pre-Fed
business cycles with post-Fed cycles. Pre-Fed we see that the economy suffered
recessions about as often as the post-Fed period but recovered must faster and
more robustly than post-Fed recessions. The pre-Fed economy never suffered a
Great Depression and no slow recoveries like the current one. They were almost
all V-shaped.
The pre-Fed economy never enjoyed massive monetary printing
or government spending as the post-Fed economy has, and yet it always recovered
from recessions with enthusiasm. That teaches an important lesson: a free
economy has a natural impetus to recovery that is very strong. It comes from
mankind’s natural tendency to truck, barter and trade, to paraphrase Adam
Smith.
One recovery in the post-Fed era proves the point. If we
combine the 1981 and 1982 recessions, separated only by six months, into one
recession, then that one was almost as deep as the Great Recession of 2008, the
worst since the Great Depression. The 1981-82 recession went so deep because
the Fed had raised interest rates very high in order to squash inflation. But
the Fed never lowered rates to boost the economy. Neither did the federal
government spend massive amounts. Business people (the micro economy) were on
their own, as they had been pre-Fed, and they lifted the US out of a deep
recession into strong growth that lasted for almost a decade.
History should cause mainstream economists to rethink their
monetary theories. Doing more of the same will not produce better outcomes. They’re
out of gas and their economies are “in irons.”
No comments:
Post a Comment